Friday, September 10, 2021

Seminar Day 1

 Follow up on seminar of Sept 9.  

 

A video explanation of the common good, by Robert Reich.

Start at about 4 minutes.

https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=J2XFfh6BDv8   ( long) 

 

A description of the current economic systems by Robert Reich.  Written before the 2008/2012 economic crisis.

Super Capitalism: The Transformation of Business, Democracy, and Everyday Life. (2007)

 

The Common Good, Robert Reich,  2018. Includes a summary of the arguments above in Super Capitalism,

 

Basic principles of the common good.-

 some general principles for consideration this semester.

 

1.   In discussing the common good, we must consider social and political rights in addition to economic measures.

2.   Not all events and policies are economically determined.

3.   Consideration of the common good extends democracy into the economic discussions.

4.   The common good is a morale choice.   Not an economic principle,

5.   Neoliberal capitalism  ( which we will examine) often works against the common good. 

 

Covid.,

 

Here is President Biden’s announcement of expanded vaccine requirements. 

 

https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=IA2SCoYl8_U

 

 

 

If you have an interest in drought.  PBS has a quite amazing series.

 

H2O Water; the Molecule, Pbs.

PBS   Episode 3. Drought. Season 1 Episode 3, 

Is inflation becoming a problem ?  Paul Krugman’s view.

 

https://www.nytimes.com/2021/09/10/opinion/transitory-inflation-covid-consumer-prices.html


To answer those questions, we need to back up and ask what it means to say that inflation is transitory, anyway. And to do that, it helps to take a long view.

My sense is that many people believe that inflation wasn’t something that happened in America before the 1970s. But that isn’t true. Consumer price data go back more than a century, and there were several episodes of high inflation over that period. The ’70s weren’t even the peak:

Image
Inflation over the long run.
Credit...FRED

What was the difference between the ’70s inflation and the inflationary spikes associated with World War I, the end of World War II or the Korean War? The answer is that those earlier bursts of inflation were easy come, easy go: The economy didn’t exactly return to price stability painlessly, but the recessions associated with disinflation were fairly brief. Ending the inflation of the ’70s, by contrast, involved a prolonged period of really high unemployment:

Image
The cost of disinflation.
Credit...FRED

But what explained that difference? In the 1970s inflation became “embedded” in the economy. The people who were setting wages and prices did so with the expectation that there would be lots of inflation in the future. For example, companies were relatively willing to give their workers wage increases because they thought that their competitors would end up doing the same, so it wouldn’t put them at a competitive disadvantage.

  • Did you know you can share 10 gift articles a month, even with nonsubscribers?
Share this article.

The question is whether inflation is similarly becoming embedded now.

We used to have a fairly easy, rough-and-ready way to answer that question: the concept of core inflation. Back in the 1970s, the economist Robert Gordon suggested that we make a distinction between the price of commodities like oil and soybeans that fluctuate all the time and other prices that are adjusted less frequently. An inflation measure that excluded food and energy, he argued, would give us a much better indicator of underlying — i.e. embedded — inflation than the headline number.

The concept of core inflation has been one of the huge success stories of data-driven economic policy. Over the past 15 years we’ve seen several surges in consumer prices driven mainly by commodity prices and much hyperventilating, mainly on the political right, about the return of stagflation or even imminent hyperinflation. Remember when Paul Ryan, the Republican representative of Wisconsin at the time, accused Ben Bernanke, the former Fed chairman, of “debasing the dollar”?

The Fed, however, refused to back off from its easy-money policy, pointing to quiescent core inflation as a reason not to worry. And it was right:

Image
Core for the win.
Credit...FRED

Unfortunately, at this point the traditional measure of core inflation doesn’t help much, because the pandemic has led to price spikes in unusual sectors like used cars and hotel rooms. So how can we find guidance?

The White House Council of Economic Advisers has been using a sort of “supercore” measure that excludes not just food and energy but also pandemic-affected sectors. This makes sense; in fact, I was arguing for such a measure months ago. But I’m aware that as one excludes more stuff from the Consumer Price Index, one exposes oneself to the charge that you’re saying that there’s no inflation if you ignore the prices that are rising.

Powell has pointed to a different measure: wage increases, which have been substantial in some of the pandemic-hit sectors but overall still seem moderate according to measures like the Atlanta Fed’s wage growth tracker:

Image
Wage-price spiral? Not yet.
Credit...Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta

Lately, however, I’ve been wondering whether the best way to figure out whether inflation is getting embedded is to ask the people who would be doing the embedding. That is, are companies acting as if they expect sustained inflation in the future?

The answer, so far, seems to be no. Many companies are facing labor shortages, and they’re trying to attract workers with things like signing bonuses. But at least according to the Fed’s Beige Book — an informal survey that is often useful for getting a read on business psychology — they’re reluctant to raise overall wages.

Just to be clear, I’m not celebrating corporate unwillingness to increase wages. The point, instead, is that companies aren’t acting as if they expect lots of future inflation, where they can hike wages without losing competitive advantage. They’re acting, instead, as if they see current inflation as a blip.

So far, then, I’m still on Team Transitory: I think things are looking more like 1951, when inflation briefly hit 9.3 percent, than 1979. And if we finally get this pandemic under control, the inflation of 2021 will soon fade from memory.


Paul Krugman has been an Opinion columnist since 2000 and is also a Distinguished Professor at the City University of New York Graduate Center. He won the 2008 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his work on international trade and economic geography. @PaulKrugman

 

New  covid mandates.

 

 





'Time for Waiting Is Over': Biden's New Vaccine Requirements Target US Workforce

"My message to unvaccinated Americans is this," said the president: "What more is there to wait for? What more do you need to see?"

 

https://www.commondreams.org/news/2021/09/09/time-waiting-over-bidens-new-vaccine-requirements-target-us-workforce

 

 

 Comments are welcome in the comments section.

Duane Campbell

 

No comments:

Post a Comment